Читать книгу How our economy really works - Brian Hodgkinson - Страница 11

3 Wages

Оглавление

A PRELIMINARY POINT about wages is that, as with rent of land, the true wages of labour may be concealed by the prevailing system of ownership. In particular, a self-employed person working in his or her own firm is really earning wages equivalent to what the firm would have to pay an employee for the services of the owner e.g. as a manager. Above this the income of the owner is profits. If his income falls below the wages level, the difference is a loss to the firm.

Britain in the twentieth century evolved into a society very heavily reliant on the Welfare State. The majority of people are mainly dependent for their living on wages which are inadequate in almost all cases to provide many of the essentials of a decent life for a family. Health services of all kinds, education for all ages, unemployment and sickness benefit, old age pensions and, for many if not all, housing require public finance on a massive scale. The term social wages has come into use to refer to this huge supplement that is needed to bring wages earned by work to a level that provides a reasonable modern standard of living.

Why is this? To some extent it is because in a democracy the majority may prefer some of these services to be provided publicly. There is a strong case, for example, for at least some health and education services to be in the public sector. Yet even so, there is no real choice about this, since the present level of wages makes proper provision for these solely out of wages impossible. Government naturally has full responsibility for defence of the realm and for law and order, but should it necessarily have to provide services that could be paid for by wage earners were wages at a considerably higher level? After all, the minority who are relatively well off often do choose private health care and independent schools.

It is a matter for public debate which services should be privately or publicly provided and, moreover, there are many different ways in which either alternative can be implemented. Politics in Britain has revolved around these questions for at least the past century. We have come to accept a fundamental division between left and right which is fostered by this issue, even if it no longer takes the basic form of capitalism versus socialism. What usually passes unnoticed is that the debate is underlain by the simple fact that wages are too low to pay for most of the services currently offered by the State.

There is, however, an even more basic aspect of the modern economy that goes unnoticed and is rarely discussed at all. Wages are too low to enable wage-earners to provide the capital required at their workplace. Owing to confusion over the meaning of the word ‘capital’, the situation cannot easily be recognised at all. Shares in a company are seen as its capital. So the question becomes ‘Should employees own shares in the company they work for?’ But the proper meaning of ‘capital’ in Economics is ‘wealth used to produce further wealth’. Wealth is everything produced by the factors of production, namely land, labour and capital itself. Put simply, capital is the means of production, excluding land, i.e. buildings, machinery, plant, office equipment, stocks of goods and so on. Shares and bonds in firms are claims on capital – and usually on land as well – and not capital itself.

Thus the real question becomes ‘Should employees in a company own the capital that they themselves use in production?’ This happens straightforwardly in a business owned by a sole trader or small partnership. But usually when capital becomes substantial employees cannot afford to provide it. A carpenter may buy his own tools; workers in a modern car factory cannot afford to buy the factory. It is now taken for granted that, except in rare cases like the John Lewis Partnership, the firm is owned by absentee shareholders, or perhaps by a handful of very wealthy entrepreneurs. Why is this taken for granted? The answer is very simple: wages are too low to enable employees to buy the very capital which they themselves use in their daily work. Were wages much higher they might either buy capital directly or raise loans on the security of their future income.

Current discussion of wage levels focuses on differentials. Workers in particular industries or with particular skills demand higher relative wages. Successful firms pay bonuses; failing ones propose wage cuts. CEOs are criticised for earning many multiples of the average wages in their companies. Top sportsmen and celebrities earn enormous amounts. Women earn less than men. And so on. These clearly raise legitimate questions. The more fundamental one, however, is ‘What determines the general level of wages?’ Such a general level is difficult to quantify. Is it the average wages, the median wage, the gross wage before deductions for tax, NIC etc., is the social wage to be added back?

What is certain is that take-home pay is what counts for the typical wage-earner, whether he or she is an executive in a City firm or a bus driver. In particular, the PAYE and NIC may just as well be seen as tax levied upon the employer of labour. Indeed its impact on production is best analysed in that way (see below p.32)

Why then is take-home pay so low? Total wages in the whole economy measured in this way consistently fall well below half of the gross national product. This means that the majority of the population, including dependents, are receiving less in total than the share distributed in one way or another as unearned income. Economists seem to have abandoned the question of what determines the distribution of income between the three factors of production, a question which was central to the researches of the founders of the subject, such as the French Physiocrats, Adam Smith and David Ricardo.

The reason for this serious omission from current analysis lies once more in the development of the British economy since the land enclosure movement. With little or no land freely available, wages are inexorably forced down to the least that workers will accept. The only alternative to being unemployed seems to be taking employment at the going rate of wages. What sets that going rate? It is clearly the lowest rate at which the employer can find workers. In other words it is set by the minimum that the unemployed worker is prepared to accept. Were he or she to demand more than that, a fellow worker gets the job. The labour market – the phrase presents a useful analogy with slavery – is loaded in favour of the employer to a degree determined by the level of unemployment. Were no other workers available the employer would have to offer more, as tends to happen in particular trades in the short-run.

Yet surely there is an alternative for the worker besides being unemployed? He can become self-employed. A minority find this a genuine option, especially in industries where small entrepreneurs have opportunities, such as currently occurs with new technology. But for the great majority of workers this is not an option. How many in retailing, manufacturing, banking, transport, power, mining and construction can do this? – even if some industries, like construction, employ workers under apparent forms of self-employment.

Why is there this lack of opportunity for self-employment? There are four major reasons. The first is inability to buy or rent a suitable workplace. Workers cannot afford to pay for a site that has the right location, which is the principal determinant of the price or rent. This is true not just for individuals who could be self-employed, but even more so for those who need to work in close co-operation with others in some kind of partnership. Few groups of employees could afford to share the price or rent of a factory, office or large store.

Secondly, there is the question of capital. Employees can rarely equip themselves with the kind of capital required by modern industries. Capital includes buildings and all the manufactured articles used in a business. Very small scale enterprises may be able to purchase hand tools. A window cleaner may afford a ladder and bucket. But what of large-scale capital, like manufacturing machinery, ships or aircraft?

Even these problems of sites and capital could at least be eased for employees if credit were available on easy terms. The low level of wages makes this impossible. Banks do not offer credit on a sufficient scale for initiatives created by average wage earners. Security for credit advanced is inadequate. Banks demand security based upon assets, especially upon land. They provide short-term credit to workers only for consumer goods and long-term credit for those who can pay the deposit on a house. Otherwise their advances for productive activities are given almost exclusively to those who already possess adequate assets to provide security, in the form often of advances against land values.

The final major reason for the difficulties of self-employment is a consequence of the other three over the course of time. Most workers today do not have the inclination or ability to cast off employment and to take to the open sea of self-employment, either alone or with others. Getting a job has become a kind of social imperative. School and universities are increasingly geared to training students for some kind of employment when they leave education. The school-leaver hopes for a job in a local firm. The graduate looks to the City of London or training as an executive in a multi-national. Employment has become the deeply entrenched norm. Those who have the will and initiative to work independently are rightly regarded as exceptional and sometimes as foolhardy.

At the root of this chief feature of the modern economy lies the question of low wages. They are low because they are set by the pervasiveness of unemployment forcing them down to a minimum. But what would be the natural determinant of the wage level if unemployment were not a serious factor? The answer follows from the explanation of economic rent. The natural level of wages is the full value of what can be produced on a marginal site, where there is no economic rent. It may appear that the better sites yield higher wages. This is to ignore the proviso that work on all sites has the same degree of effort and skill, if the economic rent is to be correctly calculated. All the excess value created on better sites is rent. None is wages, except where actual differences of effort and skill are present.

Another way of looking at this is to consider an employer of labour. He or she will not pay higher wages to one employee rather than another just because the former works on a superior site. They do the same work, so he pays the going wage. A shop assistant in Oxford Street in London does not earn significantly more than a shop assistant in a provincial town. Yet the value that one produces may be well in excess of the other’s. Indeed the employer might validly claim that he has to pay rent for the site that produces higher value, so why should he pay extra wages for the higher value in addition to the rent. Yet a further explanation of the relative uniformity of the wage level is that were excess wages paid on the better sites, workers would move to take advantage of them, until the wage rate was restored to the general level.

The London allowance does not invalidate this, since it merely takes account of the higher living costs in the capital city, so that real wages there are more or less at the general level for the whole country.

None of this means that differentials between wages in different occupations do not arise. They may be very large, but are caused by genuine variations in natural ability, training or character, not by the location of the work. There may also be irrational differentials regarding gender, race or age. Once more location is irrelevant. Location profoundly affects the value of the product of work on a particular site (though not usually the price of the product) but not differentials between wage levels arising from the nature of the worker. In fact, the differentials arising from location, which are economic rent, are far greater than worker differentials.

That wages are low in today’s economy is not as obvious as it was in the days when children ran around without shoes and many families lacked the basic necessities of life. Poverty takes new forms, such as the necessity for two family members to earn wages in order to pay for a mortgage on a house. Nowadays the proliferation of technological devices obscures the poor quality of housing and the standardisation of cheap food and clothes. Moreover, whilst consumer goods and services have undoubtedly become more available, the relative living standard of workers compared with those with unearned wealth and income has fallen substantially. A mark of this excessive inequality is the widespread desire amongst the majority trapped by low wages to gain access to the degree of wealth of the minority by fortuitous means: gambling, speculation in paper assets, and especially by getting on to the ‘housing ladder’ whereby rises in land value offer benefits that in one year may even exceed annual take-home pay. Meanwhile the value placed upon work by workers themselves and their self-respect as the real producers of prosperity for their families and for society diminishes. ‘Something for nothing’ becomes the unspoken epigram of the economy.

How our economy really works

Подняться наверх