Читать книгу Bootleggers & Baptists - Bruce Yandle - Страница 5

Оглавление

Preface

Just over 30 years ago in the May/June 1983 issue of Regulation magazine, a short piece appeared in the publication’s “Viewpoint” section. It was called “Bootleggers and Baptists: The Education of a Regulatory Economist” (Yandle 1983).1 Only four pages long, the article set forth a new theory of regulation, one that seemed consistent with the facts surrounding a large number of regulatory experiences. Using the economist’s standard concepts of supply, demand, and market forces, the theory was summarized as follows:

Politicians need resources in order to get elected. Selected members of the public can gain resources through the political process, and highly organized groups can do that quite handily. The most successful ventures of this sort occur where there is an overarching public concern to be addressed (like the problem of alcohol) whose “solution” allows resources to be distributed from the public purse to particular groups or from one group to another (as from bartenders to bootleggers). (Yandle 1983, 14)

In 1999, after 16 years spent observing Bootlegger/Baptist dynamics, the theory was described again in Regulation, this time a bit more tightly:

Here is the essence of the theory: durable social regulation evolves when it is demanded by both of two distinctly different groups. “Baptists” point to the moral high ground and give vital and vocal endorsement of laudable public benefits promised by a desired regulation. Baptists flourish when their moral message forms a visible foundation for political action. “Bootleggers” are much less visible but no less vital. Bootleggers, who expect to profit from the very regulatory restrictions desired by Baptists, grease the political machinery with some of their expected proceeds. They are simply in it for the money. (Yandle 1999b, 5)

The evolving theory filled a small niche in the growing field of public choice economics, a study area that represents a broad effort to apply economic principles to the area of politics pioneered by Nobel laureate James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock (1962).

The theory takes its name from the classic example of laws requiring liquor stores to close on Sundays, which were supported by both alcohol bootleggers and anti-alcohol Baptists—with both groups willing to spend valuable resources in pursuit of such laws. The happy bootleggers eliminated competition one day a week, and the devoted Baptists could feel better knowing that demon rum would not be sold openly on their Sabbath day. Of course, no one will ever see bootleggers carrying signs in front of a state house seeking political support when closing laws are up for reauthorization. The point of the theory is precisely that they don’t have to: the Baptists lobby state house members for them. For success to occur, according to the theory, a respectable public-spirited group seeking the same result must wrap a self-interested lobbying effort in a cloak of respectability. Both members of the politicking coalition are necessary to win. The Baptists enable accommodating politicians to say the action is the “right” thing to do and have folks believe them. The bootleggers laugh all the way to the bank—and may occasionally share their gains with helpful politicians.

Since the publication of that original 1983 article, the theory has been applied to countless regulatory situations. Today, it seems just saying “Bootleggers and Baptists” in a conversation about a regulatory struggle is enough to trigger an explanation of an otherwise curious episode.

The Regulation article has become something of a classic in the small world of regulatory studies and has defined much of its author’s career as a regulatory economist. As a rough measure of the theory’s popularity, a June 2013 Google search for “Bootleggers and Baptists” yielded 51,700 hits. Obviously, not every one of these results is about regulation: some may actually be about bootleggers (with a lower-case b) and Baptists! To put this into perspective, a Google search for “Laffer curve” returned 269,000 hits, and a search for “Lady GaGa” yielded 507 million. We would be the first to admit that those who get their thrills from studying regulation constitute a small tribe.

Although the cumulative tally of Bootlegger-and-Baptist hits is interesting, we believe the phrase’s profile over time is even more noteworthy. For the period January 2010 to June 2013, the count is 15,300. For the years 2007 to 2009, there were 1,920 hits. The three years 2004 through 2006 saw 329 hits, and 2001 through 2003, just 271. The theory is 30 years old, but the recent explosion in the number of hits generated suggests the word is just getting around. At least that is one explanation.

A more subtle explanation exists, however. First, regulatory activity is a growth industry. Growth in Bootlegger/Baptist media references is a product of that industry. Because of this growth, an extensive and dense lobbying network has been built that now encompasses every significant part of America’s political economy. Instead of investing in new plants, private hospitals, and universities and taking their chances as capitalists in a relatively free market, Bootleggers and Baptists prefer regulations that wall out competition. They want subsidies that keep weak and obsolete enterprises afloat, and when things still don’t work out well, bailouts paid with taxpayer dollars. Put another way, Bootleggers and Baptists, just like other normal people, respond to incentives. Lobbying for pork often pays a whole lot better than struggling to bring new and better goods to market—at least in the short term. Put another way, political incentives cause Bootleggers and Baptists to become anti-capitalists, participating in what former Office of Management and Budget (OMB) director David Stockman and others term “crony capitalism” (Moyers 2012). In that sense, the count of Google hits is a crude barometer of capitalism’s health. More hits mean poorer health. We are pleased that the Bootlegger/Baptist theory is part of a growing conversation on regulation but alarmed that Bootlegger/Baptist interaction is occurring at such a high pace.

Other commentators are alarmed as well. Writing in Newsweek magazine, George Will (2009) called attention to the theory and applied it to health care legislation funded by an increase in the federal cigarette tax, implying that the government may need more tax-paying smokers. Making reference to our theory, Max Borders (2012) proposed the development of a crony capitalism mitigation index. Borders even devised components for the index that would include the dollars per employee firms receive from government grants and contracts along with the campaign donations, per employee, contributed to aspiring presidents. After commenting briefly on California’s approval of funds for initiating a bullet train in the Central Valley with green jobs justification, Peter Gordon (2012) recommended that a Bootlegger/Baptist prize be awarded annually to recognize the most egregious examples of wasteful political action.

We aren’t quite ready to manage an annual contest for the ugliest special interest engagements, but we are convinced that the rising tide of crony capitalism, or what we would call Bootlegger/Baptist capitalism, is drawing some seriously critical attention to capitalism itself. Capitalism has taken lots of hits recently. Everything from bailed-out banks and auto companies to subsidized solar product firms that fail spectacularly leaves the public with the feeling that the marketplace is seriously flawed. Anti-capitalist messages seem ubiquitous. Yet the proposed remedies for the system’s failings all seem to involve more government regulation, which means more opportunities for Bootleggers and Baptists to line their purses with transferred rather than newly produced wealth.

How the Book Is Organized

With capitalism under misguided attack and with just over 30 years having passed since Bootlegger/Baptist theory first saw the light of day, we think it is time to update and add new muscle to the theory. This book seeks to do more than retell the Bootlegger/Baptist story. A lot has been learned about regulation over the last 30 years as a host of empirical studies and new economic theories have produced new insights. We seek to include the essence of this work in our book—but not just for the sake of padding our bibliography. Rather, weaving new knowledge into an old theory extends the theory and enables us to offer more carefully structured explanations of what is going on in our world—and why capitalism, the most productive way to organize wealth production that improves human well-being, is again threatened.

Our aims in this book are the following:

• To provide a richer, more detailed presentation of the theory and thereby situate it within a growing body of literature that seeks to explain government action in ways that yield richer forecasts of regulatory outcomes

• To present an illustrative collection of Bootlegger and Baptist episodes, organized in categories that can be linked to empirically observable economic effects

• To show that our account is not just a theory of political economy but rather a fundamental theory of human behavior that can be found beyond the halls of government because it emerges from basic and universal evolutionary forces

• To provide a series of in-depth applications that demonstrate the power of the theory in illuminating old and new regulatory episodes in a variety of governance situations

Our book has two parts. The first part focuses on theory while providing numerous applications. Chapter 1 describes federal regulation’s explosive growth during the 1970s and 1980s, when the theory was germinating, and presents an array of Bootlegger and Baptist stories stretching from Magna Carta to President Barack Obama’s 2012 efforts to coordinate U.S. energy producers. We organize these stories into four modes of Bootlegger/Baptist interaction, which we use throughout the book. The chapter also provides evidence of regulation’s effects on U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) growth.

Chapter 2 connects the theory to the discipline of public choice economics with a focus on the Bootlegger side of the story. Here we examine a stream of economic thought that has emerged to explain regulatory activities. We build this account by reviewing discussions of regulation that have appeared in the Economic Report of the President over 45 years. Doing so enables us to illustrate how the ideas of academic scribblers shape the mental models of presidents and their senior staff as they attempt to explain and communicate their actions. Chapter 3 speaks to the question: Why Baptists? Why do politicians find offering moral justifications necessary for actions they seek to take when serving their constituents? Why not an economic or patriotic justification? This chapter reaches into philosophy, experimental economics, and evolutionary psychology to answer the question and concludes that politicians must always offer a “Baptist” justification for their actions if they hope to survive in the political realm.

The book’s second part is a collection of specialized case studies, each illustrating an important facet of Bootlegger/Baptist theory. Chapter 4 begins, naturally enough, with the struggles over sinful substances that gave our theory its name. Here we describe regulatory episodes involving alcoholic beverages, tobacco products, and marijuana. In each case, Bootlegger/Baptist theory explains how certain rules arose in the first place and how they disappear when a Bootlegger/Baptist coalition breaks down. The alcohol regulation story is about the industry’s successful cartelization by government, acting at the behest of moral lobbyists. Similarly, the tobacco story explains how anti-smoking crusaders successfully obtained regulation that actually strengthened the tobacco industry’s profits. And as strange as it may seem, the marijuana story is about efforts to legalize pot openly opposed by the illegal growers themselves, with an unwitting assist from moralists committed to the view that everyone must not get stoned. This chapter exposes how Bootleggers undermine and manipulate even the most seemingly pure social causes, all while appearing to be at odds with the Baptists who—typically, though not always—are rallying against them.

Chapter 5 applies the theory to one of its most fertile fields—environmental regulation. We focus on the debate over global climate change, beginning with the 1997 Kyoto Protocol and then describing frustrated attempts by various interest groups to establish stricter U.S. regulation of greenhouse gas emissions. The story we tell is about Bootleggers who seize upon such regulations as a way to gain markets and grow profits, joined by environmental Baptists who lobby for emission reductions. Ours is a story of coalitions that form and split, of Bootleggers who openly join Baptist efforts, and ultimately of failed efforts to “do something” about carbon emissions. We show how the ultimate results of noble-minded efforts to effect change in the public interest prove to be neither noble nor in the public interest, but instead a product of Bootlegger manipulation.

The financial collapse of 2008 and the organization of the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) are the subject of chapter 6. TARP’s injection of federal funds into banking and other institutions was devised during some of the darkest days of the financial crisis, when White House officials were operating in uncharted territory. With all the constitutional barbed wire cut and pushed to the side, cabinet members acted to form cartels involving the nation’s largest financial institutions. Our theory is used to explain the rise and fall of TARP support and to show how banks, initially eager to be on TARP’s receiving end, became even more anxious to escape its clutches. This chapter in particular shows how Bootlegger activity without Baptist support is a dangerous business and detrimental to all parties involved.

Chapter 7 addresses the most significant Bootlegger/Baptist story of our time: the rise of Obamacare. The passage and implementation of health care reform simultaneously provided health care access to a larger share of the population, cartelized a major part of the U.S. economy, and guaranteed an expanded health care market for the insurance industry, all while disappointing many of the very parties involved with its construction. This chapter offers insights into how the interaction between the relevant Bootleggers and Baptists wound up producing a bill that many wanted but few are now willing to claim as their own, because of its failure to address health care costs.

Chapter 8 concludes the book by summarizing our key points and exploring a fundamental question: Is there a Bootlegger/Baptist endgame? We close with final thoughts on the theory and its ability to explain at least part of the political economy puzzle.

A Personal Note

We wish to offer deep appreciation to those who provided critical support to us in developing and expanding Bootlegger/Baptist theory and in producing and publishing the book. We acknowledge with deep appreciation the inspiration and guidance provided by regulatory scholar and former Federal Trade Commission chair and OMB director James C. Miller III. We hope that Miller’s noted insistence on clear thinking, tough-minded analysis, and understandable prose are found throughout the book. We also thank Richard Wagner, whose inspiring, eclectic take on the relationship between market and political domains is both pathbreaking, and perhaps accordingly, underappreciated. For similar reasons, we thank Bart Wilson, who continues to push the boundaries, and thereby the veracity, of what experimental economics can teach us. Our universities, Clemson University, George Mason University, and Johnson and Wales University, provided invaluable support as well as inspiration for our scholarly activities.

Although the ideas and papers that have emerged from our academic work have been essential to the book’s development, there would be no book if not for the support of the Searle Freedom Trust and Cato Institute, which respectively funded our enterprise and published the book. In addition to providing funds, Searle president Kim Dennis urged us to the task. Cato executive vice president David Boaz guided the publication process with the able assistance of Cato research fellow Julian Sanchez, who reviewed and commented on the entire manuscript. To Kim, Cato, David, and Julian, we extend our heartfelt appreciation. We are also deeply grateful to colleagues who read and commented on the manuscript. Chief among these is Roger Meiners, who worked through the complete manuscript offering many useful comments for revision along the way. We are indeed grateful to Roger and, as with other readers, we hold him blameless for our final product. Other readers include Dan Foster, David Rose, and Bart Wilson. Comments and criticisms received from these scholars made the book far better and much more readable. Of course, we note that the final product is ours. We alone are responsible for errors of fact or logic that remain in the pages to follow.

We close on a very personal note. The book is the product of a grandfather–grandson effort: Bruce Yandle, the grandfather; Adam Smith, the grandson. We are both economists and students of regulation, public choice, and the market process. Our collaboration has been ably assisted by a person especially important to us, Kathryn Yandle Smith, former newspaper editor and professional writer, who read and commented on the entire manuscript as it was being written, revised, and written again. We have already noted that errors that remain are ours; improved readability and logic of thought are due to Kathryn’s generous effort. She did wonders while navigating the often turbulent waters occupied by her determined father and son.

Bootleggers & Baptists

Подняться наверх