Читать книгу From Empire to Europe: The Decline and Revival of British Industry Since the Second World War - Geoffrey Owen - Страница 15

Modernisation in France

Оглавление

The fall of France in 1940 has been described as ‘a psychological avalanche that buried pre-war certainties and created a new landscape on which reformers could build anew’.21 From it sprang a collective sense of national failure, and a conviction that fundamental reforms were needed to reverse the country’s economic decline. France appeared to be trapped in a state of permanent inferiority vis-à-vis its neighbour on the other side of the Rhine. Breaking out of this trap was the over-riding objective for post-war French governments. It was to be achieved by industrial modernisation and by preventing Germany from dominating Europe as it had done before the war. The hope was that, if this twin-track policy could be implemented quickly, France would displace Germany as the strongest industrial power on the Continent.

France’s backwardness could be traced partly to the slow pace of industrialisation in the nineteenth century, partly to the crippling effects of the 1930s depression. France had kept pace with the German states in the early phase of the industrial revolution, but the governments of the Third Republic, established in 1870, did not regard the promotion of industry as an important policy objective. Prosperity and social harmony were thought to depend on preserving a balance between agriculture and industry; Germany and the US, with their pell-mell rush for industrialisation, were not seen as models which France should imitate. This did not prevent an impressive French performance in some of the industries of the second industrial revolution. The French motor industry, for example, was the largest in Europe before the First World War, and France was also the leader in aircraft production. In the 1920s modernising elements in French business sought to propagate scientific management, mass production and other American techniques. But with the onset of the Depression, which came later in France than in other European countries and bit more deeply, French industry reverted to a defensive and inward-looking posture, with an increase in cartelisation and greater reliance on colonial markets.

This was the legacy which faced General de Gaulle’s provisional government when it was installed in Paris in September 1944. The government was a coalition in which the three main parties were the Communists, the Socialists and the Christian Democrats or MRP (Mouvement Républicain Populaire). The Communist Party, then at the peak of its influence, did not seek to promote a revolution, but rather to retain its hold on power, to preserve the unity of the left and to ensure that France did not align itself with the US-dominated Western alliance. It was also eager to participate in the task of national recovery, pressing its trade union allies to increase production and to refrain from strikes.

The economic programme was a compromise between the disparate elements in the coalition. Most of the basic industries, including electricity, gas and coal, were taken into public ownership, as were the leading banks and insurance companies (the nationalisation of Renault was a special case, prompted by the owner’s collaboration with the Pétain régime during the war). While these measures gave the government control over some key industrial sectors, they were not part of a comprehensive plan to direct the economy from the centre. Pierre Mendès-France, minister of national economy in the provisional government, tried to formulate such a plan, which would be administered by a strong planning office attached to his department. But he was opposed by other ministers, notably René Pleven at the Ministry of Finance, a former businessman and close ally of de Gaulle. Mendès-France resigned in the summer of 1945 and the Ministry of Finance established a dominant influence over economic policy.

The shift away from socialism became more pronounced when the Communists left the coalition in 1947. In April of that year an unofficial strike broke out at Renault in protest against the government’s wages policy. The strikers were at first denounced by the Communist Party. But as support for the strike spread, the Communists came under intense pressure to reverse their stance. When they did so, the government insisted that the maintenance of its wages policy was a matter of confidence, and that if the Communists were not prepared to support it they should resign. What emerged after 1947, under governments of a predominantly centrist or centre-right composition, was a distinctively French form of managed capitalism. Its inspiration was not a coherent body of doctrine akin to Ordo-liberalism in Germany, but the conviction on the part of an influential group of politicians, economists and government officials that the archaic structures of the French economy could be reformed only through purposive intervention by the state.

A central figure was Jean Monnet, appointed by General de Gaulle in January 1946 to head a small planning body, the Commissariat Général au Plan. Monnet was a businessman who had close ties with the US and he greatly admired the dynamism of American industry. He was also well aware, given France’s dependence on US aid, that any modernisation plan had to be framed in a way which was credible to American policy-makers. Monnet was convinced that French industry had to be made fit enough to face up to international competition. The first step was to rebuild and expand the basic industries which had been damaged in the war. The first Monnet Plan, published at the end of 1946, gave priority treatment to six sectors – coal, steel, electricity, railways, agricultural machinery and cement – which were given privileged access to public funds. In other industries modernisation commissions were established, consisting of government officials, businessmen and trade union leaders. The Planning Commission had no powers of compulsion, but the planners were able to put pressure on firms by using the government’s control over the allocation of credit, foreign exchange and essential raw materials.

Many of the targets set in the first plan were missed, and there may have been over-investment in basic industries to the detriment of the rest of the economy.22 But the existence of the plan, and the skill of Monnet and his colleagues in persuading businessmen to co-operate with it, helped to change attitudes.23 The choice, Monnet insisted, was between modernisation and decadence, and this was a slogan which struck a chord in the country at large. The drive for modernisation affected civil servants as well as businessmen. The old administrative élite – products of the Ecole Polytechnique and the other grandes écoles – had played little part in the reforms that followed liberation; many of these officials had served in the Vichy administration, and they were widely blamed for contributing to the stagnation of the inter-war years. But de Gaulle believed that his plans for restoring the grandeur of France depended on a cadre of highly trained administrators dedicated to the service of the state. To combat the narrow-minded conservatism of the older schools, a new graduate school of public administration, the Ecole Nationale d’Administration (ENA), was set up in 1945. All senior civil servants were recruited through ENA; its curriculum was broader and less technical than that of the older schools. Although ENA did not democratise civil service recruitment in the way that some of its architects had hoped – its students continued to come mainly from the Parisian middle and upper classes – it helped to propagate a technocratic view of the state as a promoter of modernisation.24 The technocrats were in command, too, in the newly nationalised enterprises. The spirit of the times was personified by the flamboyant head of Renault, Pierre Lefaucheux, a businessman who had played an active part in the resistance. Although he had socialist sympathies, he saw the company as ‘une entreprise-pilote’, setting an example of dynamism and innovativeness for the rest of the motor industry.25

The first Monnet Plan had an important international dimension.26 What was at stake was France’s place in Europe and, above all, its relationship with Germany. If France could take advantage of Germany’s defeat to build up its industrial strength, the balance of power on the Continent might be permanently altered in France’s favour. In this context the steel industry had a special significance. The French steel mills, concentrated mainly in Lorraine, had always obtained most of their coking coal from the Ruhr. The expansion of steel-making capacity envisaged in the Monnet Plan was based on the assumption that German steel production would be held well below its pre-war level. This would ensure that adequate supplies of coal would be available to France and that the enlarged French steel industry would take over from Germany as the principal supplier to Continental markets. In the aftermath of the war, when Allied policy towards Germany was in its punitive phase, these ambitions seemed realistic. But after the announcement of the Marshall Plan France had to accept that West Germany would soon be created as a sovereign state and reintegrated into the European economy. While the Americans recognised French sensitivities over the Ruhr, they were not willing to contemplate permanent curbs on German steel production. France had to find alternative means of fulfilling its industrial ambitions while protecting itself against German domination.

The outcome of this reappraisal came in 1950 with the proposal for a European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC), presented to the world by Robert Schuman, the foreign minister, but largely devised by Jean Monnet. The primary motive was political. It was a way of dealing with one of the most contentious issues in Franco-German relations and establishing a new partnership between the two countries. It was also an imaginative approach to European integration, and for that reason attracted the immediate support of the Americans. John Foster Dulles, Secretary of State, saw the Schuman Plan as ‘brilliantly creative’, while President Truman described it as ‘an act of constructive statesmanship’.27 But Monnet also saw the plan as a way of shaking up a conservative and cartel-minded steel industry, he regarded the Treaty of Paris, which established the Community, as Europe’s first antitrust law. In the event, the impact of the Community on competition was more limited than Monnet had hoped. Although intra-European trade in steel increased, national governments continued to intervene in the industry for political and social reasons. Yet the treaty marked a shift away from the privately regulated cartels of the past and established a concept of European interdependence which could be applied to other sectors.

For the shift to go further, a transformation would have to take place in the attitudes of French businessmen. France was a highly protected country, and in the early 1950s some 40 per cent of its overseas trade was with the colonies. Monnet and his colleagues knew that intra-European trade offered far greater possibilities for industrial modernisation than trade with the Empire. A possible way forward was to continue the sectoral approach, extending to other industries the same principle which had been applied to coal and steel. But the Beyen Plan, which proposed the elimination of tariffs on all industrial goods among the six member countries of the ECSC, involved a much bigger leap in the direction of free trade.28 The initial French reaction was hesitant, partly because of the weakness of the balance of payments, but by 1955, when the foreign ministers of the six ECSC countries met in Messina to consider the Beyen Plan, France’s trade position had improved and the advocates of free trade were in a stronger position to argue their case. As they saw it, sectoral arrangements along the lines of the Coal and Steel Community had serious limitations. ‘The French renaissance had to be completed by pushing the whole of French manufacturing into a competitive common market … Either France renounced liberalisation, modernisation and its hopes for the future, or it took the economic risk.’29 That risk was taken when France signed the Treaty of Rome in 1957, and the next decade saw a rapid reorientation of French exports towards its Common Market partners (TABLE 3.2).

For France, as for Germany, intra-European trade was crucial to the high rate of economic growth which was achieved in the 1960s. But France’s approach to economic policy was more erratic than that of the Federal Republic. The most glaring failure was persistent inflation; successive governments were unable either to control public spending or to impose a German-style monetary policy. Consistency in economic management was not helped by the fragmentation of the political parties, leading to a series of short-lived coalitions. While the withdrawal of the Communists in 1947 had removed the risk of a swing to the left, none of the conservative parties commanded the same solid national support as the Christian Democrats in West Germany. General de Gaulle formed his own party, the Rassemblement du Peuple Français (RPF), rather than accept the leadership of the MRP. Political and social divisions were exacerbated by the colonial wars in Indo-China and Algeria, culminating in 1958 in a political crisis, the return of General de Gaulle to power and the inauguration of the Fifth Republic. The new constitution provided for a stronger presidency, and economic policy became more coherent.

TABLE 3.2 Destination of French exports 1952–73 (per centage of total)


The reform process in France differed from Germany in two other respects. First, the French government did little to promote internal competition. Although a law against price-fixing was passed in 1952, enforcement was lax, and cartels continued much as they had done in the 1930s. Second, there was no overhaul of labour relations. Like their German counterparts, most French employers before the war had been hostile to trade unions, and resented the concessions which had been forced on them at the time of the Popular Front government in 1936. After liberation in 1944 there were hopes that relations between capital and labour could be put on a new footing. One of the first acts of the provisional government was to require all firms with more than 100 employees to establish comités d’entreprises, or plant committees, through which managers and employees could work together to increase production. These committees were helpful in coping with the short-term problems of reconstruction, but there was no fundamental change in the labour relations system. The comités d’entreprises left behind ‘a residue of mundane achievement and a sense of unfulfilment’.30

Thus the impetus for reform in France after the war was more limited than in Germany, and left some old institutions and attitudes intact. The biggest changes were the national consensus in favour of industrial modernisation and the recognition that a new relationship with Germany had to be forged. One of Monnet’s most valuable contributions, according to his biographer, was to promote a shift in attitudes among France’s ruling élite ‘from the pretensions of a moth-eaten great power to the realism of a medium-sized but ambitious economic one’.31 It was the weakness of France’s position after the war which encouraged bold and imaginative solutions to its problems, and in this context the Schuman Plan was crucial.32 The European Coal and Steel Community allowed France to assume a position of leadership in building post-war Europe, and pointed the way to the fuller exposure of French industry to German competition.

From Empire to Europe: The Decline and Revival of British Industry Since the Second World War

Подняться наверх