Читать книгу Engine of Inequality - Karen Petrou - Страница 15
How to Fix Financial Policy
ОглавлениеThe first fix is for the Fed to see America as it is, not as it was. Top Fed officials came of age in the 1970s and 1980s when America was among the most equal nations in the world. At that time, monetary-policy theory could rightly assume that aggregate data about income and wealth represented the vast majority of Americans.
Now, due to American inequality, the country as a whole no longer buys goods and services or invests as old models predict.47 Vast differences in US educational levels have resulted in large numbers of low-skilled, low-wage workers who do not move where jobs are plentiful or otherwise respond to economic signals as conventional monetary-policy models anticipate.48 We will see in Chapters 6 and 7 how antiquated analytics have been destructive not just to Fed thinking, but also to its ability to transmit monetary policy. Mistaken analytics have also done irreparable damage to equality because policy inadvertently but all too effectively benefits only the wealthiest among us.
The second fix goes to the heart of this mistaken monetary-policy construct, requiring the Fed to stop rescuing financial markets in trickle-down giant programs and instead to support ground-up growth. This starts with stepping back and letting markets function normally instead of rushing in to save them each time a little stress shows itself in a bad day on Wall Street. We will see in Chapter 6 that the Fed has mistakenly made policy since the early 2000s based on an expectation that market rescues lead to a “wealth effect” that then benefits the rest of us after the wealthy have had their fill. Unprecedented inequality ever since is clear proof that the wealth effect is all too effective for the wealthy, but an accelerant to economic hardship for everyone else.
As we will also see, the wealth effect has made markets prone to another risk. Known as “moral hazard,” it occurs when investors take high-risk bets, insouciant in the knowledge that the Fed will always bail them out. It did in 2008 and again in 2020, making financial markets rise ever higher even as unemployment rose to unprecedented heights. The Fed readily admits it doesn't know how to normalize the trillions now on its hands in the wake of all its post-COVID rescues, suggesting very slow normalization should anything like normal ever again be possible. We will see in Chapter 11 how to take the Fed's heavy hand off the market as quickly as possible without overturning the market at the same time.
The third fix needed for an equality-focused policy reckons not only with the anti–wealth equality effect of the Fed's giant portfolio, but also the anti–income equality impact of ultra-low interest rates. The lower these go, the less companies spend on investment, the harder it is for lower-skilled workers to find jobs, and the farther behind family savings fall from any hope of buying a home, going debt-free to college, or securing retirement. Equality will advance with a smaller Fed portfolio and higher interest rates. These are counterintuitive to traditional thinking, which assumes that the bigger the Fed and the lower the interest rates, the better it is for bottom-up growth. Since 2008, the Fed followed this traditional playbook and became by far the biggest it's ever been, driving rates below zero after taking even a little bit of inflation into account. The result was inequitable, slow growth and a fragile financial system that crumpled virtually in minutes when markets realized how dangerous the pandemic would prove. As we will see, it's simply impossible to have a stable financial system without economic equality no matter the trillions the Fed deploys to stabilize markets. Trickle-down monetary policy has proven disastrous to both equality and stability. The Fed indeed must quickly remedy this not just by normalizing its portfolio, but also by gradually raising interest rates to provide for what I call a “living return” – that is, a rate enough above that of inflation to give small savers growing nest eggs from which to start families, buy homes, or retire in comfort.
And, federal financial regulators should redesign post-crisis regulation so that its burden is borne equitably by all financial companies, especially those companies that offer higher-risk financial products to vulnerable households. This would expand the supply of equality-essential financial services beneath an umbrella of regulation that protects at-risk consumers. It would also ensure that privateering financial companies die by their own hand instead of receiving the trillions of dollars in bailouts proffered during the great financial crisis and again as COVID struck. We'll see how asymmetric regulation creates equality and financial-system risk in Chapter 8, with solutions laid out in Chapter 10. These include new ways to apply like-kind rules to like-kind companies, changes to key rules to increase credit availability for low- and moderate-income (LMI) households, and new financial institutions focused solely on economic equality dedicated to under- and unserved communities, including those of color.
Finally, the Fed and bank regulators must reckon quickly with the new, digital forms into which money is quickly being transformed. Financial policy builds the engine of economic inequality, but money is its fuel. If it joins financial policy in revving up the most powerful – i.e., the wealthiest – parts of the engine by flooding them with gas, the US financial system will quickly become still more inequitable and thus even less stable. We will see in Chapter 9 how a new central-bank digital currency that harnesses the fuel in a newly designed equality engine would set us quickly on a more level, tranquil road.
We will also see in Chapter 10 how to ensure that new rules or institutions aimed at equality actually do what they're told. Purpose and profit do not rest easily within private-sector financial companies. So it's also time for the federal government to step in with targeted financial products and newly designed financial institutions. There must also be tough rules to ensure that those given lucrative benefits to serve the less well-off do not repeat past instances in which financial companies hid behind do-good charters and did all too well only for themselves. Classic cases in point are the $5.5 trillion US government–sponsored enterprises Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. In the lead-up to 2008, they invested millions in advertisements echoed by nonstop lobbying touting the “American dream of homeownership” and how they made it real. In 2008, both of these companies' failures initially cost taxpayers $187.5 billion,49 but their former executives to this day enjoy posh retirements funded by the enormous salaries and lush pension plans doled out before the crash.
Polarized like so much else in American discourse, the current financial-policy debate contrasts two ends of the policy extreme: government intervention in the financial market or a wholly market-driven financial system. This is indeed the contrast between socialism in full flower and capitalism red in tooth and claw. John Kenneth Galbraith once observed, “Where the market works, I'm for that. Where the government is necessary, I'm for that.”50 This is insightful, but of course also facile – it's not hard to be for working markets and an effective government; it's hard to know which is which.
The rest of this book is an effort to determine when markets work well for equality-enhancing finance and when the government needs to step in with monetary policy, regulation, and even government-backed programs such as new “Equality Banks” that provide vital financial services when the private market falls short.