Читать книгу Out of Work - Richard K Vedder - Страница 27
EXPECTATIONS AND THE NEW CLASSICAL ECONOMICS
ОглавлениеAround 1970, some respected economists, notably Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps, started to sharply question the long-run efficacy of the prevailing Keynesian/underconsumptionist theory.21 They questioned whether demand stimulus could maintain sustained high-employment levels. They intimated that the negative inflation-unemployment relationship suggested by the Phillips curve was unstable in the short run and nonexistent in the long run.
The evidence from the 1970s supported these and other critics, and a new group of younger economists—the New Classical school—formulated innovative theories that put greater emphasis than previously on the role of expectations. The thrust of these arguments was that government policies designed to stimulate demand would induce behavioral changes among individuals in the private sector, changes that would render the policies ineffective.22
For example, suppose the government announced big spending increases to stimulate aggregate demand or, alternatively, that the Federal Reserve took steps to increase the money supply by creating new bank reserves. Individuals and businesses, sensing the inflationary potential of such policies, would alter their behavior in several ways. Banks would become more concerned about getting paid back their loans in dollars of depreciated purchasing power, and would demand higher interest rates. Thus deficit-financed new government spending would, indirectly, “crowd out” private spending that is sensitive to interest rates. While some proponents of rational expectations disagree with this conclusion, they nonetheless agree that deficit financing would not stimulate aggregate demand because of increased private savings that would mean a lower propensity to consume goods and services by the private sector.23
Also, expansionary federal fiscal (or monetary) policies would lead labor unions to become more militant, demanding larger wage increases. Higher wages, other things equal, would reduce employment (figure 2.1). The demand and employment stimulus of governmental policy, then, if anticipated, would be offset by behavioral modification among the populace. Only if the population were deceived would the policies work.24
In the most extreme form, the new theoretical perspectives evolving in the 1970s and 1980s implied both that cyclical unemployment would not exist for any length of time, and that governmental policies could almost never be effective, even in the short run. Regarding the first point, at least one advocate of the new theoretical approach, in all seriousness, explained away the unemployment of the 1930s as a spontaneous surge in the demand for leisure—involuntary unemployment simply could not exist.25 As Franco Modigliani characterized this interpretation, “What happened to the United States in the 1930s was a severe attack of contagious laziness.”26
It should be pointed out that some of the New Classical economists have exhibited views on the unemployment-wage relationship that is the opposite of that of the original neoclassical/Austrian perspective. For example, when low wages occur, some New Classical economists have argued that workers find leisure less costly in terms of wages foregone, leading them to withdraw from the labor force until wages improve. If actual real wages are less than expected wages, this can lead to labor-force withdrawal. Thus while the New Classical economists are similar to the earlier neoclassical and the Austrian economists in believing that “wages do matter,” they do not adopt the simple view that unemployment is primarily the result of an increase in the relative price of labor.
Other New Classical economists have used other arguments to try to explain unemployment and business cycles. Some have rediscovered Joseph Schumpeter, who argued that fluctuations in the rate of innovation and technological change largely determined business cycles.27 Others have emphasized the unemployment effects of costs associated with sectoral shifts in employment.28
So-called New Keynesian economists turned to microeconomic analysis to question some of the New Classical postulates. Some emphasized wage rigidity.29 Some studies have rediscovered another old hypothesis, namely that firms can maintain labor productivity at high levels by keeping wages high during periods of unemployment; this is the so-called “efficiency wage” argument.30 Others have discussed the stickiness of prices.31 Still others have argued that even with wage and price flexibility, you do not necessarily get economic stability.32
We should note that European economists have struck something of a “middle road” by formulating complex models in which excessive real wages are sometimes the explanation for so-called “classical unemployment,” while at the same time price rigidities in goods markets are permitted to create “Keynesian unemployment.”33 This is consistent with the general trend of theoretical developments of the past two decades: an increasing tendency to look more closely at the microeconomic foundations of unemployment, even to the extent, on occasion, of analyzing unemployment in terms of real wages and other phenomena.
To recapitulate, while economists were generally indifferent to unemployment during the first third of the century, they tended to blame the phenomenon largely on wages in excess of an equilibrium market-clearing level. In the second third of the century, underconsumptionist thinking came to dominate in the form of Keynesianism. Unemployment was largely attributed to insufficient aggregate demand for goods and services. Unlike the previous orthodoxy, Keynesian theory supported activist macroeconomic government policies. The last third of the century has been characterized by a variety of theories competing for dominance. Keynesianism and underconsumptionism have been in at least partial retreat, while theories denying the effectiveness of policy actions have dominated, along with some renewed attention to the role of wages in explaining unemployment. Nevertheless, the ghosts of Keynesianism and underconsumptionism are still with us in many ways.
The remainder of this book explores the historical record of unemployment in the United States. In particular, we will examine the original neoclassical wage-oriented theory and its effectiveness in explaining observed variations in unemployment. A number of questions will be explored, such as: Was the neoclassical theory really ever a dominant orthodoxy in the United States? Was its almost total passage from the intellectual scene in the 1930s justified on the basis of historical experience? Does the Keynesian (or other) explanation fit the experience better? Was the great governmental involvement in the macroeconomy that followed from the Keynesian revolution a success or failure? What seems to have caused the rise in noncyclical unemployment? Why is it that the incidence of unemployment has varied so dramatically with age, sex, and race in recent decades, but not earlier? These are but a few of the issues with which we will deal.