Читать книгу Wealth - Yuval Elmelech - Страница 16

Wealth as portfolios

Оглавление

Personal wealth is made up of various assets (real estate, stocks, business, etc.), which are embedded in a range of markets, require specific levels of maintenance and care, and vary in the degree of control that the owner has over them. Certain assets are subject to special tax rates, and the ability of owners to liquefy and transfer assets is not uniform (Clignet 1998; Wolff 1996).

There are a few general typologies of asset categories. Taking into consideration the different economic functions of assets as well as their liquidity (their capacity to be converted into cash), economist Edward Wolff proposed three categories of wealth (Wolff 1996): “financial wealth” covers household net worth minus net equity in owner-occupied housing, because such property requires more time to be converted into cash; “marketable wealth” (or net worth) is the net value of all “marketable or fungible” (liquid) assets, minus any liabilities or debts; and “augmented wealth” adds pension wealth and social security wealth to household net worth.

Another common classification system separates assets into two categories. The first includes liquid or financial assets that have no intrinsic value but represent contractual claims to assets: stocks, bonds, checking accounts, retirement accounts, and so on. The second category encompasses tangible or “real” assets that have consumption value: vehicles, primary residence and other real estate, businesses, and other assets, for example miscellaneous non-financial ones (jewelry, works of art, fine furniture).

Relatedly, a third typology focuses on the function and key purpose of assets and divides household wealth into two general categories: functional or non-productive assets, which have use value for the family as an economic unit; and financial assets. Functional assets—the family’s vehicles and main residencemake up a significant share of the net worth held by the vast majority of households. Owned for their use value, they nonetheless tend to produce economic benefits while servicing their owners. For example, car ownership improves mobility and can indirectly enhance job opportunities and access to services (Lerman and McKernan 2008; Piketty 2014: 47; Oliver and Shapiro 1995: 105), while main residences provide shelter and space for families to live, raise children, work, and entertain in. The equity held in a main residence can appreciate over time and can be used as collateral against loans, which enhance the household’s consumption, investment, and savings. These assets are typically visible to the public and recognized as status symbols.

Unlike functional assets, financial assets are less conspicuous. They are held in bank accounts, college savings accounts, loans, corporate stocks, and retirement accounts and are more unevenly distributed within the population. Whereas functional assets are wanted for their use value, the primary motive for possessing financial assets is their exchange value and the expectation of future price appreciation and income.

Additionally, while a family’s main residence is immobile, more difficult to liquidate, and subject to price changes according to local housing markets, financial assets require fewer intermediaries and are more easily transferred and exchanged in global markets (Clignet 1998: 95). Consequently, financial or income-producing assets such as stocks and bonds represent liquid wealth and are particularly important for household finance on account of their capacity to be easily converted into cash. The distinction between financial and functional assets is especially common in research on income stratification. This line of study often separates the sources of income into labor income (wages and earnings), which is earned in exchange for labor effort, and asset-based income, which takes the form of dividends, interest, rent, or capital gains from the sale of stocks or real estate (Piketty 2014: 17, 48). For scholars interested in wealth, the latter kind of income stream is of great importance because it does not require the same degree of time and effort as labor income does.

Finally, the distinction between productive and non-productive assets also bears on the conceptually fundamental distinction between social class and social status. While ownership of productive property is associated with class and economic power, ownership of consumption goods—or “property of private appropriation” (Newby et al. 1978, quoted in Knight 1982: 4)—is tied to inequality based on lifestyle and social status (Saunders 1978; Sorensen 2005). As Parkin (2014: 195) puts it, “[i]t is clearly necessary to distinguish property as possession from property as capital, since only the latter is germane to the analysis of class systems.”

Wealth

Подняться наверх