Читать книгу Building the Empire State - Brian Phillips Murphy - Страница 8

Оглавление

NOTE ON BANKING TERMS


At its core, a bank is an organization that lends money and extends credit to people on the basis of its assets and their ability to repay obligations. Those assets could be money—piles of gold and silver coins, say—or anything with a recognizable value as collateral. For example, land banks, sometimes called country banks, accepted mortgaged real estate as a form of capital, enabling landlords to turn their normally illiquid holdings into paper banknotes. Money or commercial banks, by contrast, preferred coined money that was called specie. Not surprisingly, cash-rich and land-poor merchants favored money banks to the land banks desired by landlords.

Organizationally, banks could be wholly private enterprises. A simple contract drawn between two partners who loaned money at interest could be considered a private bank. Incorporated and joint-stock banks were composed of shareholders who each held fractional ownership in the institution, which they could buy and sell. The owners did not need to know each other because the institution itself was governed by a stable set of rules and regulations and administered by an elected board of directors and hired staff.

A joint-stock company that received an incorporation grant gained rights and legal privileges that distinguished it from other companies lacking such a useful instrumentality. A corporation possessed a fictitious legal “person-hood” that allowed its directors and shareholders to sue and be sued in court as a single entity and to hold common property as shares changed hands and membership on the board of directors rotated. An incorporated bank might also operate on a larger scale than an unincorporated joint-stock sibling because it enjoyed a privilege of limited liability, protecting shareholders from being responsible for debts incurred by the bank above the amount of their investments. An unincorporated partnership that went bankrupt could haunt generations of heirs and descendants, but the failure of an incorporated bank wiped out only its shareholders’ equity investments in the enterprise; their other assets were shielded from legal claims. Incorporated banks, then, possessed advantages that other commercial enterprises and unincorporated institutions did not. With those privileges, however, came an enormous amount of discretion; bankers chose who they would do business with, making those banks desirable for investors and well-connected borrowers but resented by those left on the sidelines. This aspect of banking became far more intense if a bank’s charter was exclusive, giving it a monopoly within a city or state by barring the creation of competing institutions.

A bank’s principal function in this period was to provide a sound medium of exchange: called banknotes, these were pieces of bank-printed money that could be redeemed on demand for gold or silver, making it a very safe and desirable form of currency.

In contrast to banks that developed in the mid-nineteenth century and are familiar to twenty-first-century readers, banks in the early republic served the interests of commercial firms rather than individual consumers by providing financiers, businesspeople, and merchants with access to credit and capital. Without satellite branches, banks typically conducted business locally, “discounting” notes—IOUs—in exchange for an equal amount of the bank’s own printed currency, minus interest. It was called a “discount” because the bank collected its interest payment up front. At a 6 percent annual interest rate, a bank would lend someone $100 for a three-month term by giving them $98.50 in the bank’s own banknotes; $100 would be due at the end of the loan. Banks discounted both commercial paper—short-term IOUs used in lieu of cash—and longer-term, renewable accommodation notes. Both types of loans had to be endorsed by guarantors known to the bank’s directors, making borrowers and endorsers jointly responsible for debts. Thus, banking privileges were personalized and reputation-dependent.

Boards of directors, cashiers, and clerks were all responsible for making sure that the paper money banknotes and checks paid by the bank were authentic, not counterfeit. But this task was mere housekeeping compared to the directors’ obligation to ensure that the bank’s customers—the recipients of its credit—were worthy of the risks entailed in allowing them to become debtors. A bank that was incorporated or formed by a joint-stock company typically loaned twice as much as its capitalization (the sum it had raised initially by offering its shares for sale). For example, a bank that sold one thousand shares priced at $500 each was capitalized at $500,000 and might loan as much as $1 million. Because the bank was extending itself in this way, each time it decided to offer credit to a client it was taking a risk. This necessarily meant that personal relationships became important factors in determining who received credit. Similarly, any person accepting a check had to make a judgment about the person passing the check, the name of the person who had signed it, and the bank’s ability to pay the check. The person who redeemed a check might be the second, third, or even fourth person to hold it. A bank, then, created networks of credit by taking risks and acting as a financial intermediary, providing tangible and reliable paper banknotes and checks that facilitated the buying and selling of goods and services in a local and regional economy.

Building the Empire State

Подняться наверх