Читать книгу Putin's Russia - Группа авторов - Страница 29

References

Оглавление

Abramov, A., Radygin, A. and Chernova, M. (2017). State-owned enterprises in the Russian market: Ownership structure and their role in the economy, Russian Journal of Economics, 3(1), 1–23.

Acemoglu, D., Naidu, S., Restrepo, P. and Robinson, J. A. (2014). Democracy does cause growth. NBER Working Paper No. 20004, NBER, Cambridge, MA. Available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w20004.

Åslund, A. (2013). How Capitalism Was Built: The Transformation of Central and Eastern Europe, Russia, the Caucasus, and Central Asia, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom.

Barro, R. J. (2015). Convergence and modernisation, The Economic Journal, 125(585), 911–942.

Becker, T. (2013). Crisis prevention, in Rosefielde, S. (ed.), Prevention and Crisis Management: Lessons for Asia from the 2008 Crisis, Chapter 6, Scientific Publishing, Singapore.

Becker, T. (2017a). Russia: Macroeconomic challenges, in Rosefielde, S., Kuboniwa, M., Mizobata, S. and Haba, K. (eds.), The Unwinding of the Globalist Dream: EU, Russia and China, Chapter 8, World Scientific, Singapore.

Becker, T. (2017b). Investment relations between Sweden and Russia, in Liutho, K., Sutyrin, S. and Blanchard, J. F. (eds.), The Russian Economy and Foreign Direct Investment, Chapter 6, Routledge, London.

Becker, T. (2018). Russia’s economy under Putin and its impact on the CIS region, in Becker, T. and Oxenstierna, S. (eds.), The Russian Economy under Putin, Chapter 2, Routledge, London.

Becker, T. and Mauro, P. (2006). Output drops and the shocks that matter, IMF Working Paper No. 06/172, IMF, Washington, D.C. Available at: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2006/wp06172.pdf.

Becker, T. and A. Olofsgård (2018). From abnormal to normal — Two tales of growth from 25 years of transition, Economics of Transition, 26(4), 769–800.

Berezinskaya, O. (2017). Investment drought in the Russian economy: Structural characteristics and turnaround perspectives, Russian Journal of Economics, 3(1), 71–82.

Bevan, A., Estrin, S. and Meyer, K. (2004). Foreign investment location and institutional development in transition economies, International Business Review, 13(1), 43–64.

Calvo, G. A. (1998). Capital flows and capital-market crises: The simple economics of sudden stops, Journal of Applied Economics, 1, 35–54.

Chappell, H. W., Jr. (1990). Economic performance, voting, and political support: A unified approach. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 72(2), 313–320.

Djankov, S. (2015). Russia’s Economy under Putin: From Crony Capitalism to State Capitalism, Policy Brief, PB15-18, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC.

Fernandez-Arias, E. and Hausmann, R. (2000, March 26). Foreign direct investment: Good cholesterol? Inter-American Development Bank, Research Department Working Paper No. 417.

Frenkel, M., Funke, K. and Stadtmann, G. (2004). A panel analysis of bilateral FDI flows to emerging economies, Economic Systems, 28(3), 281–300.

Fortescue, S. (2018). The political economy of Russia: Is it changing, in Becker, T. and Oxenstierna, S. (eds.), The Russian Economy under Putin, Chapter 12, Routledge, London.

Gorodnichenko, Y. and Roland, G. (2016). Culture, institutions and the wealth of nations, Review of Economics and Statistics, 99(3), 402–416.

IMF. (2018). World Economic Outlook. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Knack, S. (1996). Institutions and the convergence hypothesis: The cross-national evidence, Public Choice, 87(3–4), 207–228.

Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: Crosscountry tests using alternative institutional measures, Economics and Politics, 7(3), 207–227.

Kudrin, A. and Gurvich, E. (2015). A new growth model for the Russian economy, Russian Journal of Economics, 1, 30–54.

Levine, R. and Renelt, D. (1992). A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions, American Economic Review, 82(4), 942–963.

Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 681–712.

Mileva, E. (2008). The impact of capital flows on domestic investment in transition economies. ECB Working Paper No. 871. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1090546.

Nivorozhkin, E. and Castagneto-Gissey, G. (2016). Russian stock market in the aftermath of the Ukrainian crisis, Russian Journal of Economics, 2(1), 23–40.

Peresetsky, A. A. (2011). What determines the behavior of the Russian stock market. MPRA Paper No. 41508.

Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A. and Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2), 131–165.

Roland, G. (2000). Transition and Economics: Politics, Markets, and Firms, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Shleifer, A. and Treisman, D. (2005). A normal country: Russia after communism, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1), 151–174.

Shleifer, A. and Treisman, D. (2014). Normal countries: The East 25 years after communism, Foreign Affairs, retrieved February 23, 2018, from https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/russia-fsu/2014-10-20/normal-countries.

Sutyrin, S. and Trofimenko, O. (2017). Do formal institutions really matter for foreign direct investments to the Russian federation? The case of FDI flows from the European Union to Russia, in Liutho, K., Sutyrin, S. and Blanchard, J. F. (eds.), The Russian Economy and Foreign Direct Investment, Chapter 5, Routledge, London.

______________________

1 Chappell (1990) shows that both approval ratings and voting depend on growth and inflation in the US.

2 Åslund (2013) discuss the transition process in Russia and other post-communist countries at more length.

3 The notion of Russia being a “normal” country was introduced by Shleifer and Treisman (2005) and then used by the authors to look at a wider set of countries in Shleifer and Treisman (2014).

4 The benefits of investments in other sectors than the extractive industries are rather obvious. However, decisions to shift government policies away from extractive industries to the benefit of other sectors would be subject to a political process with strong opposing forces as discussed in Fortescue (2018).

5 In a recent study, Berezinskaya (2017) notes that there has been no growth in investment measured in constant ruble terms in recent years and this is the first prolonged stagnation of investments since Putin became president.

6 Both Bevan et al. (2004) and Frenkel et al. (2004) find significant negative Russian dummies in cross-country regressions of FDI determinants.

7 Fernandez-Arias and Hausmann (2000) discuss the links between institutional quality and the level and composition of capital flows and note that better institutions increase overall flows but that the share of FDI in total flows is negatively correlated with institutional quality.

8 Calvo (1998) provides a more in-depth analysis of “sudden stops”, which apparently come from a banker that said that “it is not the speed that kills, it is the sudden stop”.

9 Capital flows in the balance of payments statistics are divided into foreign direct investments, portfolio flows and “other” flows that include bank loans between domestic and foreign entities. There are also unaccounted flows that fall under the heading “errors and omissions”, which capture both statistical errors and unregistered flows that would include capital flight that do not go through the banking system or other official channels. As a country’s economic and financial system matures and the statistical agency develops, this component tends to shrink. The balance of payments statistics also makes a distinction between flows in the private sector versus government institutions. This may sound as a relatively straightforward split, but in a country like Russia where many of the large companies have a significant share of government ownership, the distinction is not as clear as it may appear. The share of government ownership in the Russian economy varies over time and across studies, but estimates suggest that the government could account for up to 70% of the economy overall and own 30–50% of asset (see Abramov et al., 2017) and that the share of the government in the economy has increased during Putin’s days in office (Djankov, 2015).

10 Nivorozhkin and Castagneto-Gissey (2016) focus on how relationships between the Russian stock market and international markets have changed significantly after the Ukrainian crisis. This is consistent with the finding here that there are more excessive volatility and negative return days in 2014/2015 than in earlier periods.

11 Peresetsky (2011) instead uses the Japanese Nikkei index since this is closer in terms of time, but since the S&P is closer to a global stock market index and this analysis is not about market efficiency, the fact that we have to use a lag of S&P to get a good specification is not an issue.

12 See, for example, Knack and Keefer (1995) and Knack (1996) for property rights institutions, Mauro (1995) for corruption and growth and Acemoglu et al. (2014) for the importance of democratic institutions for growth.

Putin's Russia

Подняться наверх