Читать книгу Economics of G20 - Группа авторов - Страница 22

References

Оглавление

Agarwal, M. (2017). The Operation of the Gold Standard in the Core and the Periphery Before the First World War, Centre for Development Studies WP 473, Centre for Development Studies, Thiruvananthapuram, Kerala, India.

Ahamed, L. (2009). Lords of Finance: The Bankers Who Broke the World, New York: Penguin Press.

Borio, C. and Toniolo, G. (2006). One Hundred and Thirty Years of Central Bank Cooperation, BIS Working Papers No. 197, Bank of International Settlements, Basel Switzerland.

Clarke, S. V. O. (1973). The Reconstruction of the International Monetary System: The Attempts of 1922 and 1933, Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 33, Princeton University.

Cohen, B. J. (2015). Currency Power, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Costigliola, F. C. (1977). Anglo-American Financial Rivalry in the 1920s, The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 37, No. 4, pp. 911–934.

De Cecco, M. (1984). The International Gold Standard, London: Pinter Publishers. Decorzant, Y. and Flores, J.-H. (2012). Public Borrowing in Harsh Times: The League of Nations Loans Revisited, Universite de Geneve, Faculty de Sciences Economique et Social, WP 12091.

Eichengreen, B. (1996). Hegemonic Stability Theory and Economic Analysis: Reflections on Financial Instability and the Need for an International Lender of Last Resort (December 9, 1996), Center for International and Development Economics Research, Paper C96-080.

Eichengreen, B. (1998). Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Eichengreen, B. and Hatton, T. (eds.) (1988). Editors’ Introduction to Interwar Unemployment in International Perspective, in Interwar Unemployment in International Perspective, B. Eichengreen and T. Hatton (eds.), Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

Findley, C. V. and Rothney J. A. (2006). World War I Reparations: Twentieth Century World, 6th ed., Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company.

Flandreau, M. (1997). Central Bank Cooperation in Historical Perspective: A Sceptical View, Economic History Review, Vol. 50, No. 4, pp. 735–763.

Gallarotti, G. M. (1995). The Anatomy of an International Monetary Regime: The Classical Gold Standard, 1880–1914, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Gilpin, R. (1987). The Political Economy of International Relations, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Kindleberger, C. P. (1973). The World in Depression: 1929–1939, Berkeley: University of California Press.

Keohane, R. (1984). After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy, Princeton University Press.

Laybourn, K. (1999). Modern Britain since 1906, London: I.B. Tauris.

Marks, S. (1978). The Myths of Reparations, Central European History, Vol. 11, No. 3, pp. 231–255.

Modelski, G. (1987). Long Cycles in World Politics, Seattle: University of Washington Press.

Moggridge, D. E. (1972). British Monetary Policy 1924–31: The Norman Conquest of $4.86, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Morrison, R. J. (1993). The London Monetary and Economic Conference of 1933: A Public Goods Analysis, The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 52, No. 3, pp. 307–321.

Moure, K. (1996). Undervaluing the franc Poincare, Economic History Review, Vol. XLIX, No. (i), pp. 137–153.

Moure, K. (2002). The Gold Standard Illusion: France, the Bank of France and the International Gold Standard, 1914–1939, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Myers, M. G. (1945). The League Loans, Political Science Quarterly, Vol. 60, No. 4, pp. 492–526.

Orde, A. (1990). British Policy and European Reconstruction after the First World War, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Organski, A. F. K. (1968). World Politics, 2nd ed., New York: Knopf.

Pittaluga, G. The Genoa Conference: Was It Really a Failure? Available at http://citescerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.1626.8385&rep=rep1&type=pdf.

Wallerstein, I. M. (2004). World-Systems Analysis: An Introduction, Durham: Duke University Press.

Warnock, B. S. (2015). The First Bailout — The Financial Reconstruction of Austria, 1922–1926. PhD dissertation, Birkbeck College University of London.

1It is always difficult to judge whether the deficit of the US is too high. Since the dollar is the international currency, there would be demand for it from other countries and therefore accumulation of reserves. This would imply a current account deficit.

2It was under 3.2% in the UK in 1920, helped perhaps by pent-up demand from the war years, and rose to 11.3% after the 1922 budget cuts and to 9.7% in 1927 (Eichengreen and Hatton, 1988). This experience is in contrast to the 33 years between 1880 and 1913, where the average rate of unemployment was 4.7% and for 21 years in this period it was lower than this (Moggridge, 1972). Also, see Orde (1990) for a discussion of performance in the immediate post-war years.

3For further details, see Myers (1945). For a discussion of economic and political ramifications of the Hungarian loan, see Orde (1990).

4For a discussion of the Austrian loan, see Warnock (2015).

5This should be compared to the Marshall Plan under which the US gave U$13 billion.

6The A and B Bonds represented the total German reparations liability of US$12 billion, an amount smaller than what Germany had offered to pay at the beginning of the negotiations.

7Germany made its last reparations payment of US$94 million on October 3, 2010, settling its outstanding debt from the 1919 Versailles Treaty and finally closing the reparations chapter.

8For a history of reparations, see Findley and Rothney (2006).

9The US and the UK agreed on the necessity to reduce reparations. The UK hoped that the US would also reduce their war debts. For a discussion of the Dawes Plan, see Orde (1990).

10The French government, by contrast, issued bonds worth 44,000,000,000 francs from 1919 to 1925 to finance reconstruction of its devastated regions.

11Hegemonic theories can be divided into the realist school and the systemic school, which can be further sub-divided. Two dominant approaches in the realist school are exemplified by Keohane (1984) and Organski (1968). Modelski (1987) and Wallerstein (2004) are the two dominant approaches in the systemic school of thought. See Gilpin (1987) for a discussion of these theories. Also see Eichengreen (1996) and Cohen (2015).

12For details regarding the central bank lending to each other, see Agarwal (2017).

13Also see Flandreau (1997).

14The motives of the Banque de France in lending to the BE are analysed in Moure (2002).

15Their attitude towards the debts owed to them which they wanted paid in full was very different from that towards other debts and reparations. The British had borrowed on behalf of many others who lacked creditworthiness in the US market, and so its ability to repay its loans depended on it being repaid. The tough US negotiating stance then and later during and after World War II reflects the desire of US to eliminate the British challenge to their power.

16Under it the central banks would hold foreign currencies instead of gold. The British wanted them to hold sterling, which the French were not in favour of.

17For the French motivations, see Moure (1996).

18Later, the French had opposed the role of the dollar in the post-Second World War international monetary system. The then French president had wanted a return to gold to end what he called the “exorbitant privilege” of the US.

19More and more countries are adopting the framework of inflation targeting where the central has the responsibility of maintaining inflation in range and has to justify any failure.

20See the discussion in Pittaluga based on an index of cooperation developed by Borio and Toniolo (2006).

21This struggle is best described in Costigliola (1977). Ahamed (2009) also describes these events in similar terms without drawing any conclusions about whether there was a struggle for supremacy.

22The establishment of the GES can be seen, and the French saw it as an attempt to foist sterling on other central banks. Cooperation among central banks, many of the newer ones, was established with loans from England and was susceptible to English influence (Pittaluga).

23They kept Russia on the sidelines and were helped by the German Russian agreement at Rapallo.

24For instance, while in 1923–1924 Strong supported British plans that linked Austria and Hungary currencies to the British pound, the Americans balked at the British attempt to link the new German currency with sterling during the Dawes Plan negotiations.

25The British ambassador to Washington summed up the problem in early 1921 as “the central ambition of American politicians is to be the leading nation in the world and also among the English-speaking nations. Apart from having the strongest navy and the largest mercantile marine they intend also to prevent us from paying our debt by sending goods to America and they look for the opportunity to treat us as a vassal State so long as the debt remains unpaid.” (Quoted in Costigliola, 1977, p. 913.)

26The Bank of France was usually represented by the deputies as Moreau; the head did not speak English.

27He provided a loan from the NY Fed of US$200 million to England and arranged for a loan of US$300 million from J.P. Morgan to provide reserves in case sterling came under pressure.

28The French tried to convert their accumulated sterling reserves to gold in order to force England to renegotiate the war time loans.

29It is interesting to speculate how the conference might have turned out if the negotiators from the United States had been able to offer war-debt cancellation, exchange stabilisation, tariff reduction and support for an IMF in order to obtain acceptance abroad of the cooperative recovery programme outlined in the president’s instructions to the United States delegation.

30For a more sympathetic evaluation of Roosevelt’s reluctance to provide the public good of monetary stability, see Morrison (1993).

31It is important to remember that after the Asian crisis of 1997 a Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) run jointly by the IMF and the World Bank was started. Under it, the working of the financial sector was studied to see whether companies were following the rules recommended by the relevant international body.

Furthermore, stress tests were conducted. Countries were subjected to such analysis. But the US refused to participate in any analysis of its financial system and we know that the 2008 crisis originated in the US financial system.

32Even at the height of the recession the BIS was calling for an increase in the rate of interest and as the reason they gave was seen to be irrelevant they gave new reasons. It is perhaps because they believed that it was impossible to change the mindset of central bankers and their prejudices would be strengthened if there was a body such as the BIS, both Keynes and White had wanted the BIS abolished.

33Even now the threats to multilateralism seem to be coming from the US. Earlier, the US had withdrawn from or not signed onto such multilateral initiatives as he law of the sea, the international court of justice or the Paris accord on climate change.

Economics of G20

Подняться наверх