Читать книгу The Handbook of Peer Production - Группа авторов - Страница 87
6 Conclusion
ОглавлениеThe organization and governance of peer production projects has to balance the independence of individual contributors and the interdependence of a collective endeavor. In‐between the promise of autonomy and the implementation of due process, peer production projects struggle with the suitable level of provision and tolerance (Kostakis, 2010). Initiatives have fed on principles of free choice and increasing individual agency. Yet they are challenged by the reality of an increasingly vast and pervasive texture of rules and requirements which should secure the accuracy and value of the resource and respond to societal expectations.
In this ongoing transformation, standards in Wikipedia have, for instance, changed from “folksy ‘description of how we do things’” to “punitive ‘the way one must do things because otherwise they will punish me’,” Lih (2009, p. 224) claimed. Being aware of these tendencies of increasing formalization, the editors of the online encyclopedia have also devised the somewhat paradoxical rule to “Ignore all rules.” It states that if a rule hinders users from improving Wikipedia it should be willfully ignored. The call to be bold and edit thus seeks to balance mushrooming specifications with the vital commitment to openness. Interestingly, this principle is not found in all Wikipedia language versions, which points to the heterogeneity of the arrangements prevalent among the myriad endeavors that make up peer production. There are forms of isomorphism where different projects follow connate social norms and rules as well as distinct institutional settings peculiar for an individual enterprise.
A blueprint for the future design and implementation of peer governance is arguably provided by Elinor Ostrom’s (1990) principles of successful common‐property regimes. They are a key reference for analyzing the provision and allocation of shared resources in “settings in which the individuals involved have exercised considerable control over institutional arrangements” (p. 61). Sustainable, long‐term settings rest on the congruence between institutions and local conditions. They are marked by collective choice arrangements where people affected by rulings should also participate in their formulation and enforcement. This kind of reciprocal responsibility also ought to foster the monitoring and conflict resolution mechanisms. Graduated sanctions allow community members to adapt penalties in accordance with the severity of wrongdoings. Ostrom furthermore points to the need for local enforcement where communal jurisdiction is recognized by external authorities, and she underscores the importance of multiple layers of organization and governance. In effect, commons‐based projects form a type of nested enterprises where productive participation is arranged at different levels that reach from small circles to the entire community.
With these directions for successful mutual and inclusive governance beyond markets or firms, Ostrom’s work on property‐rights regimes seems to be a natural fit. Indeed, many peer production projects have sought to emulate some of her advice (Aaltonen & Lanzara, 2015; Forte & Bruckman, 2008; Keegan & Fiesler, 2017; Kiesler et al., 2011; Pentzold, 2011; Viègas et al., 2007). Yet while Ostrom deals with the allocation and provision of scarce natural resources, peer production mostly centers on information goods whose use is nonrival (Hess & Ostrom, 2011). In consequence, urgent issues revolve around the creation of common resources, not their consumption. This is unfinished business. In order to expand and reinforce the collective capability of contributors, peer production’s institutions have to be continuously aligned with the dynamically unfolding conditions and requirements of its projects.