Читать книгу Applied Mergers and Acquisitions - Robert F. Bruner - Страница 77
Overvaluation of Stocks and the Asymmetry of Information
ОглавлениеFive studies associate the appearance of waves with buoyant capital market conditions: a rising stock market and low or falling interest rates. M&A waves are procyclical; they occur in line with increases in stock prices.5 There is some disagreement about whether peaks in M&A lead or lag peaks in stock prices.6 Nelson (1959) suggests that rapid development of a capital market (in countries where it had been previously undeveloped) may spur M&A activity. Golbe and White (1988) argued that merger activity increases when bargains are available, as measured by a low ratio of market value to replacement costs (Tobin’s Q). Recent theories by Shleifer and Vishny (2001) and Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2003) consider an alternative explanation: that stock markets may overvalue stocks. Managers of firms have their own inside assessments of the intrinsic values of their firms. Because they know more than investors on the outside (economists call this “information asymmetry”), these better-informed assessments may vary from the prices in the market. When the prices in the market exceed the insider assessment of value, rational managers can enhance the wealth of their current shareholders by selling stock. Thus, equity issuance will tend to occur when stock prices are high, an idea advanced by Myers and Majluf (1984).
Recognizing that share-for-share deals were the equivalent of an equity issue by the buyer, Shleifer and Vishny (2001) modeled the behavior of buyer managers during “hot” and “cold” equity markets and found that merger activity (especially waves), form of payment, and who buys whom are driven by the relative valuations of the pairs of firms, synergies, and the time horizons of the managers. For instance, stock acquisitions are used by buyer managers who perceive that their shares are overvalued in the market—during buoyant stock markets, this would explain why we observe relatively more share-for-share deals; and it would explain the preponderance of cash deals in cold markets. They write, “Stock acquisitions are used specifically by overvalued bidders who expect to see negative long run returns on their shares, but are attempting to make these returns less negative than they would be otherwise. The examples of the acquisition of Time-Warner by AOL and of build-up of high valuation conglomerates with stock illustrate this phenomenon.” (Page 19) This would also explain the periodic appearance of momentum-style acquisition strategies (see Chapter 17 for more on momentum acquiring). Shleifer and Vishny conclude:
We do not assume that markets are efficient, but rather that the stock market may misvalue potential acquirers, potential targets, and their combinations. In contrast, managers of firms are completely rational, understand stock market inefficiencies, and take advantage of them in part through merger decisions. This theory is in a way the opposite of Roll’s (1986) hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers, in which financial markets are rational, but corporate managers are not. In our theory, managers rationally respond to less than rational markets. (Page 2)
Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2003) (RV) build on this framework. While Shleifer and Vishny offer a rationale for the behavior of buyers, why should targets accept stock offers from buyers whose shares are likely to be overvalued? RV suggest that targets are canny enough to assess the misvaluation of the buyer and target, but not canny enough to correctly assess the value of synergies—this is because of an information asymmetry between the buyer and target in which the buyer has a better idea of the possible economic gains between the two firms. They write, “Thus, when the market is overvalued then the target is more likely to overestimate the synergies even though he can see that his own price is affected by the same overvaluation.” (Page 2) Ang and Cheng (2003) give empirical evidence in support of the overvaluation/information asymmetry theory. Based on a sample of 9,000 observations from 1984 to 2001, they find:
Acquirers are much more overvalued than their targets. Successful acquirers are more overvalued than the unsuccessful ones. The probability of a firm becoming an acquiree significantly increases with its degree of overvaluation, after we control for other factors that may potentially affect the firm’s acquiring decision. Since overvalued acquirers could only gain from their misvaluation by paying for the acquisitions with their stocks, we postulate and verify that stock-paying acquirers are substantially more overvalued than their cash-paying counterparts…. The probability of stocks being utilized as the payment method significantly increases with the acquirer’s overvaluation. Long-term abnormal returns of the combined firms in stock mergers are negative. (Pages 3–4)
The new theory of overvaluation and information asymmetry does little to explain the clustering of M&A activity in industries, but it advances our understanding of merger waves and lends a couple of practical implications. First, it helps explain the association between the buoyant stock markets of the 1960s, 1980s, and 1990s and the coincident large merger waves. Second, it presents a framework for thinking about the form of payment (about which more is said in Chapter 20). As a practical matter, then, this theory invites executives to consider three questions:
1 What is the level of the market today? Deal makers will be influenced by the relative levels of valuation. The practitioner can compare valuation multiples such as the price/earnings ratio or market/book ratio for the market averages today, with those prevailing in the past. During 1998–2000, such a comparison showed the market to be highly valued (“irrationally exuberant” in Robert Shiller’s terms).
2 What is the valuation of my firm relative to the market? If you want to figure out where your firm is likely to be in the food chain, focus on its valuation relative to other firms. The new theory suggests that more overvalued firms will be buyers, and less overvalued firms will be targets.
3 What do I know that the market doesn’t? This is one of the fundamental questions M&A practitioners should always ask. The new theory lends weight to it by suggesting that most practitioners ask it. The timing and form of payment of M&A activity is basically motivated by a disparity between one’s own assessment of the intrinsic value of the firm and the market price. The theory suggests that the main basis for believing that your estimate of intrinsic value is better than the market price is because of an information advantage.