Читать книгу The New Environmental Economics - Eloi Laurent - Страница 12

Malthus and sustainability analysis

Оглавление

In 1798, in his brief and lugubrious essay on the principle of population, where cynicism quarrels with fatalism, Reverend Thomas Robert Malthus states what he believes to be the iron law of human tragedy. We are, says Malthus, caught between production and reproduction: Our incontinent desire to procreate violently comes up against the limits of our ability to feed our offspring. The tragic is mathematical: If the food subsistence grows at an arithmetical rhythm (1, 2, 3, 4 ...), the population grows in turn at a geometric rhythm (1, 2, 4, 8 ...). So, while only resources only add up, humans are multiplying. Humanity is running to ruin, and of its own doing. The reasoning seems irresistible: “At the end of two centuries, population and means of subsistence will be in the ratio of 256 to 9, after three centuries, 4096 to 13.” If they want to prosper, humans must learn to control their own growth.

Nearly two and a half centuries later, Malthus’ mistake is glaring: “Human population and well-being have grown together, exponentially. The great desynchronization promised by the pessimist pastor has turned into an abundance of prosperity absolutely new in the long history of human history. To put it simply, there are seven times more people on the planet than in Malthus’ days and their life expectancy is twice as high as when he made his gloomy prediction. The irony is that Malthus was pretty good at describing the situation that prevailed over the seven million years of human presence on the planet before he took the pen. But, at the precise moment when he states his theory, it became empirically false. The first industrial revolution (of which Malthus did not see the premises around him), the successive agricultural revolutions, the progress of medicine, the emergence and development of the welfare state (which he could not imagine and would most certainly have resented), will prove him more and more wrong over the decades, until today.

But, if Malthus was wrong on substance, he was not mistaken about the form: A great desynchronization, potentially more destructive than the one he had imagined, did indeed start on his watch. Consider, to measure it as precisely as possible, five fundamental indicators of human development for about a century: population, human development (income, health, education), gross domestic product (GDP), carbon dioxide emissions, and extraction of natural resources (Graph 1.1).


Graph 1.1 Three ages of human development* (factor of increase: 1900 = 1)

* The historical human development index aggregates, on an equal weighted basis, an income indicator, an education indicator and a health indicator.

Source: Human Development Report database, Global Carbon Project. Leandro Prados de la Escosura, World Human Development, 1870–2007, Review of Income and Wealth, 61 (2), June 2015: 220–247 and Maddison Project Database and Krausmann Fridolin, Simone Gingrich, Nina Eisenmenger, Karl-Heinz Erb, Helmut Haberl, and Marina Fischer-Kowalski, 2009. “Growth in global materials use, GDP and population during the twentieth century.” Ecological Economics, 68 (10), 2696–2705

What can we discern? There are clearly three periods, three ages of human development whose characteristics differ quite sharply: In the first age, the first half of the twentieth century, population increases and human development grows even faster. Malthusian pessimism is spectacularly invalidated: “More people on average experience greater well-being. CO2 emissions are growing a little faster than human development, but at a slow pace, extraction of natural resources grows at the pace of human development and Gross Domestic Product (GDP) reflects, exaggerating a little, a new prosperity of the human species, seemingly compatible with the preservation of its habitat, the biosphere.”

During the second period, between 1950 and 1980, the great desynchronization begins: While the growth of human development slows down and is gradually caught up by that of the population, CO2 emissions and GDP are racing and natural resources extraction is multiplied by 2.5. At the end of the period, in 1980, CO2 emissions and GDP grew by a factor of ten compared with the beginning of the twentieth century, tripling the pace of population growth and human development.

The third age of human development is the time of illusion: While population and human development are stabilizing at the same rate of growth, CO2 emissions continue to grow much faster than both, and natural resources extraction doubles again, while GDP, completely disconnected from human reality, masks the gravity of the ecological crisis (in that period, biodiversity declines substantially).

The increase in human development in the second half of the twentieth century has been achieved at the cost of environmental degradation (in the form of CO2 emissions) four times higher than in the first half of the century, even though the population increased only slightly more than in the years between 1900 and 1950 (2.4 against 1.6). It is therefore mostly the qualitative means of human development that are in question – and not just the quantitative demographic pressure – in the explosion of post-Second World War environmental degradation. The beginning of the twenty-first century is even more “inefficient” when we relate human well-being to its ecological cost. Emissions growth increases at its highest rate ever (almost 75%), contrasting with the growth of human well-being and population (only 10%) and up to 1 million species are threatened with annihilation because of human activity.

To sum up: Between 1900 and 1950, it was necessary to triple CO2 emissions to obtain a doubling of human development. Between 1950 and 2000, this same doubling required more than a quadrupling of CO2 emissions. At the beginning of the twenty-first century, a doubling of human well-being would be achieved at the cost of a multiplication by almost eight of the CO2 emissions responsible for climate change. In other words, Malthus has his accounting revenge and we are faced with a new crisis of paces: To the now synchronized arithmetic growth of the population and well-being responds the geometric progression of environmental degradation that will eventually overcome human recent and fragile prosperity.

How do we get out of this trap? Faithful to the idea that there is no problem whose absence of solution cannot be exhausted, we can think first of all that this great desynchronization will be solved by itself, in the fashion of Malthus, by amputation of human well-being and disappearance of the least resilient part of the population. The health consequences of climate change are, in fact, becoming better known and more and more tangible (see Chapter 9). Climate change and the ecological crises it will aggravate have, no doubt, the power to destroy in a few decades the human progress of the last two centuries. The Malthusian stagnation was explained precisely by famine crises, which “naturally” regulated the level of the population. Malthus himself was in favor of abandoning the poorest part of the population to its fate by suppressing the laws that could support it.

This Malthusian method is the implicit choice made by human societies at the beginning of the twenty-first century: About 90% of the so-called natural catastrophes of the last twenty years are linked to climatic phenomena, and they have affected the existence of 2.3 billion people, who live for the most part in the poorest countries on the planet. The current rate of degradation of the biosphere promises the world’s most vulnerable hell on Earth.

Malthus leaves us with a haunting intuition of our sustainability crisis and a dismal response to it. David Ricardo, over whom Malthus exerted a strong intellectual influence, offered more humane responses in dealing with the inescapable limits of human development on a finite planet.

The New Environmental Economics

Подняться наверх